Monday, October 10, 2016

Transportation Models and Theories (Part Two)

By Alfonso Llanes
October 10, 2016
Abstract

Different transportation theories were covered in part one of these papers,  therefore, part two will propose a new theory based on “waterways corridor” method to analyze freight rates and how these freight rates can be established by carriers. The principle proposed here is based on routing traffic through ocean, air, or ground corridors each with a “toll” at each segment the route either from the applicable international water corridors or the domestic traffic lanes to a final destination. This paper focus on ocean freight only and will derive a corresponding equation based on the “tolling” of traffic corridors and the fact that all carriers must use the same trade lanes. This argument can be reduced to a numerical expression with two parameters: Knowns and unknowns where every ship entering the trade corridor has a “toll” known factor of distance-cost no matter what the size of the ship is. It follows that domestic sea-lanes are the next “toll” to be added which is also a known quantity, so, the remaining unknowns are the variable quantities of canal crossings and destination seaboard ports-costs. Therefore, this argument simplifies the equation to the problem of finding the marginal cost with one dependent and one independent variable based on the following facts:

1.       Ocean routes have an established transit time or “toll” for all carriers.
2.       Sea Lanes have an established transit time or “toll” for all carriers.
3.       Straits have an established transit time or “toll” for all carriers.
4.       Canals have variable costs according to the size of the ship.

5.       Ports in the coastal waterways have variable costs according to the size of the ship.

Graphic depiction  of waterways, geographic obstacles and location of ”tolls” to navigation.


Photo-depiction of geographic elements of water passages and port terminals feeds.



However, this model can only be used to solve individual rates per unit of cargo. It follows that a second model is needed to exact a proportional assessment of port costs or canal crossings for varying ship sizes and whether this proportion varies directly or inversely with a new ship size. The advantage of this analysis is that technical innovation of ships can be included in a proportional matrix and a scalar.
Economic pricing theory is based on the equilibrium price calculated when supply and demand is in balance. This price does not exist in actual trading processes except in special and rare cases; it is only an ideal or theoretical price level, which at best is only approximated in the real world.
The Principle of "Charge What the Traffic Can Bear” tell us that freight rates for different commodities are determined on the basis of the capacity of an individual commodity to bear the burden of freight.
In formal economic terms, the law of diminishing marginal returns states that as the number of new inputs, the marginal product of an additional input will at some point be less than the marginal product of the previous input. Neoclassical economists assume that each "unit" of input is identical. Diminishing returns are due to the disruption of the entire productive process as additional inputs are added to a fixed amount of capital. (Same size port and facilities but more ships to attend)
David Hummels, Georg Schaur  (2012) argue that delays to shipping navigation of one day in transit or port is equivalent to an ad-valorem tariff of 0.6 to 2.3 percent. They continue with the comparison of transportation cost-benefit analysis between airplanes for fast time-sensitive- delivery and the slower but larger weight ships can carry as components of trade.
They provide the following relationships in the comparison between Air Premium Value =fa −fo = (1+air charge/air value)-(1+vessel charge/vessel value). Air Premium Weight =ga/go = (air charge/air weight)/ (vessel charge/vessel weight).
One concern for carriers is whether  regulatory incentives will continue to encourage individual owners to invest in modernization of the fleets, however, older ships need to be demolished or else it would lead to increases in global capacity, clogging ports of origin-destination and putting downward pressure on freight and charter rates.

Strategies for hybrid-transportation and tactics for leaning inventories.

A number of techniques corresponding to this shift have emerged such as consolidation of merchandise along shared routes.  Shippers are also finding ways to consolidate in multi product containers, pallets, or cartons to optimize capacity utilization. Finally, finding and evaluating alternative modes of transportation by using intermodal rail services, instead of canal crossings or trucking services, for long-haul freight for instance, going across the US or Canada by rail rather than the Panama Canal.
Surface carriers on the other hand, are focusing more on critical mass costing, marginal costs delivery patterns, time of day mileage user fees and the various ratios size-weight, time-distance and tracking costs by either GPS tolling or cellphone text communication where available.

Many developing countries mainly in Africa and Oceania, pay 40-60% more on average for international transport of imported goods than developed countries do. The main reasons for this situation are to be found in these regions’ trade imbalances, pending port and trade facilities legal reform, as well as lower trade volumes and shipping to/from connectivity. Legislators in these countries could partly help the situation with investments in infrastructure and legal framework reforms, especially, in shipping systems and Customs’ clearance and administrations.
On many shipping routes, especially for most bulk cargoes, ships sail full in one direction and return almost empty as round trip freight is charge to the shipper. Having spare capacity, carriers can offer backhaul cargoes at a much lower freight rate than front haul rates. For instance, freight rates from China to North America are higher than on back haul for North American exports to China.

UNCTAD analysts estimate that global seaborne shipments have increased by 3.4 per cent in 2014 which is the same rate as in 2013. These volumes exceeded 300 million tons bringing the total of maritime trade to 9.84 billion tons per year. The total seaborne capacity at the beginning of the year for the commercial fleet consisted of 89,464 vessels, with a total tonnage of 1.75 billion dwt.
The distribution of percentage by product is as follows:


Greece still is the largest ship-owning-country, next to Japan, China, Germany and Singapore.
Together, the top five ship-owning countries control more than 50% of the world tonnage.
Five of the top 10 ship-owning-countries are in Asia, four are European and one is from the Americas.
According to UNCTAD, Maritime Review, (2015) the container-carrying-capacity per carrier-country tripled between 2004 and 2015, but the average number of companies that provide services from/to voyages decreased by 29%. Both trends illustrate two sides of the same issue: as ships get bigger and companies’ objective is to achieve economies of scale, there are fewer remaining companies in individual markets.

CONCLUSION

The defining feature of diminishing marginal returns is that as total investment increases, the total return on investment as a proportion of the total investment (the average product or return) decreases. For example, 1 docked ship can deliver merchandise to a port that adds 1 unit of economic gain to the area.  A second ship docked would add 1.5 units and a 3rd ship would produce 1.75 units of economic gain. 
In numeric terms, the i th produce additional economic gains to the area.{\displaystyle {\frac {1}{2^{i-1}}}} 
The return from the first ship is 1 s/unit. When 2 ships dock, the return is 1.5/2 = 0.75 s/unit, and when 3 ships are docked, the return is 1.75/3 = 0.58 s/unit, as the same amount of dock space is shared by additional ships.
It follows that as dock space remains constant and more ships are added delays to unloading arise and as a consequence, a diminished marginal return occurs as the fixed dock space is being shared:


Another way to measure the best route to a port is applying Dijkstra’s algorithm in graph theory:
Finding Shortest Path with Dijkstra’s Algorithm
Initial Condition

Probing For Shortest Route




Transportation modeling in general, was formalized by French mathematician Gaspard Monge in 1781. Since then many others have contributed to the theory and its economic implications. Below is the original formalized expression by Monge.
It corresponds to finding an optimal matching between the source points and the target points from
R---R² in Euclidean space. Russian Leonid Kantorovich improved on Monge’s model 150 years later by introducing his duality principle in set theory.  The informal way of interpreting Kantorovich and his duality principle is explained by Caffarelli as:
A shipper needs to move and pay for a certain amount of sand c(x; y) which is transported from place x to place y. Both the amount of excavated sand and the amount of sand pile are equal and at fixed points of origin-destination.
Kantorovich expanded this model by liberalizing the origin-destination and transportation of the sand without regard to order. Where the cost of loading ϕ(x) of one ton of sand at place x, and a cost ψ(y) for unloading it at destination y will be the same no matter the order the loads are taken or delivered in the given space R---R².

In 1965 Lotfi A. Zadeh introduced the idea of Fuzzy Sets but it wasn’t until Hans-Jiirgen, Zimmermann in 1985 introduced the application of fuzzy logic to many human endeavors including transportation. In the three decades since its inception, the theory has matured into a wide range of concepts and techniques for dealing with complex phenomena that do not lend themselves to analysis by classical methods based on probability theory and” fuzzy” logic. This novel idea is opposed to the principle of a conventional sets for which an element is either a member of the set or not as 0 or 1. A fuzzy set can be anywhere between 0 and 1 or what is called approximate reasoning and also, where probability theory plays a major role in the distribution values between 0 and 1.

Source: Applied Mathematical Sciences, Vol. 6, 2012, no. 11, 525 – 532

This mathematical modeling applied to transportation can be structured applying fuzzy logic to common crisp numerical methods as regression analysis, matrices, probability, and statistics and so on. In simple terms, fuzzy values are to be found between and within a given range in a closed interval for a given set, i.e., 1000 freight rates. It follows that we can get the constant of proportionality k in a boundary of values in a 6 month period-interval if we assign a value for  at time 0 and then solve for a separable differential equation in a closed interval. i.e., at


REFERENCES


David Hummels, Georg Schaur January 2012, TIME AS A TRADE BARRIER. NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH .Cambridge, MA 02138.

Krugman, Paul(1991) 'Increasing returns and economic geography'.  Journal of Political Economy Vol. 99, No. 3 (Jun., 1991), pp. 483–99.

C. Broda and D. Weinstein. 2006. "Globalization and the Gains from Variety,"
Quarterly Journal of Economics, Volume 121, Issue 2

Eaton, Jonathan and Samuel Kortum. 2002. "Technology, Geography, and
Trade." Econometrica, 70 (September): 1741-1779.

Lugovskyy, V. and Skiba, A., 2009. "Quality Choice: Effects of Trade, Transportation Cost, and Relative Country Size,"

Berthelon, Matias and Freund, Caroline L., "On the Conservation of Distance in International Trade" (May 6, 2004). World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 3293.

Gilman, Sidney (1983), The Competitive Dynamics of Container Shipping, University of Liverpool Marine
Transport Center.

Harley, C. Knick, (1988) “Ocean Freight Rates and Productivity, 1740-1913: The Primacy of Mechanical Invention Reaffirmed”, Journal of Economic History, 48, 851-876.

Mohammed, Saif I. and Jeffrey G. Williamson. "Freight Rates And Productivity Gains In British Tramp Shipping 1869-1950," Explorations in Economic History, 2004, v41(2,Apr), 172-203.

Combes, P., Lafourcade, M. (2002) Transport costs, geography, and regional inequalities. 2894, C.E.P.R. Discussion Papers.

Oyama, T., Taguchi, A. (1991) On some results of the shortest path counting problem. Abstracts of the OR Society Meeting (Kitakyushu): 102-103.

UNCTAD (2015) Review of maritime transport. United Nations Conference on Trade and Development,
Geneva.

Pedrycz, W. [1989] . Fuzzy Control and Fuzzy Systems. New York, Chichester, Toronto .

Hadi Basirzadeh . An Approach for Solving Fuzzy Transportation Problem (2011) Shahid Chamran University Ahvaz, Iran.