Optimizing Freight Rate Functions
Using discrete mathematics to describe the behavior of
transportation networks has to include Riemannian geometry in consideration of
geographical curved space and gradients. This issue alone can represent an immense
challenge for developers who may be very competitive in computer science but
not in the business side of transportation networks. Specially, when defining
which method and what set of metrics are to be used for taking measurements across
the entire spectrum of the system being developed.
Freight managers recognize that they need to allocate in separate
sets direct and indirect costs for the vehicles, the routes, as well as the size,
and capacity, for determining the unique transportation platform’s weight and cubic
space available for the market at a price that defines the break-even point for
a specific case in question.
The short cut for calculating a freight rate is of course to
add all the fixed and variable costs and divide them by the vehicle’s capacity
on either weight or space in order to establish a freight rate per unit of cost.
Intuitively, this is a reasonable argument but other hidden costs can upset the
balance in unexpected ways.
A more labored approach is to use a tool such as a modified
Cobb-Douglas
production function
used in economics to determine the marginal product of capital (K) and the
marginal product of labor (L) and replace them with applicable variables for
freight transportation. The method prosed here is to use a theoretical freight
rate divided with fractional exponents that can result in a model that can
measure returns of scale with a given
set of variables and within a specific route or market.
For example, if a freight vehicle makes a round trip but
only carries cargo one way then the utilization factor is ½ its
capacity. In this case, the backhaul is negative but the round trip cost is
positive. So, if no backhaul cargo is available a round trip charge would need
to be applied, however, this may not be possible because route competition or
some other market condition don’t allow it. Freight component can be
represented with a fractional exponent representing the utilization factor as
it is applied to the theoretical model.
The next problem to
be assign a solution is stowage factor and freight managers will try to
maximize the amount of cargo that can be carried for either weight or volume. Under these circumstances, vehicle capacity
becomes an issue of dimensional weight factoring. That is the factor at
which the unit platform arrives at its weight or volume capacity for a given
freight rate. So, another fractional exponent can be inserted into the cost function.
Determining maximum carrying value on a limited transportation
platform by either weight or volume is an issue that can, in many cases,
determine success or failure of a transportation company. The theory behind the
problem has been endlessly studied with “the knapsack problem” which, relates
to combinatorial optimization between weight, space and value. Given a set of cargoes, each with a weight, a volume
and value, freight managers must determine the number of each unit that can be
included in a collection of items equal to a given limit where the total commodity-freight-value is as large as
possible. Thus, the problem becomes an issue of optimizing a vehicle utilization
factor for any given trip. As a result, another fractional exponent
representing commodity value can be added to the function.
Distance from origin to destination can be a constant
for a route but not for off route trips and must be considered accordingly as
yet another exponential fraction that can be added to the overall equation.
Once all the exponents have been determined the function should provide a
theoretical optimized approximation to an original set previously defined by
capital, labor and energy at a break-even of the function.
It follows that if a freight manager who targets
optimization based using the modified Cobb-Douglas can assign random values to
the function to perform an initial evaluation between the break-even and
marginal cost incremental for Utilization,
Stowage, Commodity Value and Distance.
This ca be abbreviated as: Freight where (F)=
a fractional exponent like 1/n taken to the
nth root and expressed on its decimal exponent equivalent of F= (
U^.25
S^.25 C^.25 D^.25
).
If we make the assumption that this equation will hold for
90% of the rate optimization cases and the remaining 10% is treated as
extraneous freight components that only apply to very few cases. For instance,
where berthing facilities are poor, port infrastructure is inadequate and/or terminal
expenses are not competitive with the rest of the world because of
inefficiencies or corruption.
Under these circumstances, freight managers can assess the
marginal effect of cost on freight rates when one or more of the factors of the
proposed freight equation domain is increased or decreased from an initially evenly
divided cost-freight-factors set at 1/4+1/4+1/4+1/4.
The following exercise using a generic freight rate of $12 for
weight or measure per metric ton constrained by market rates in a given route
is found to have a $4 utilization rate cost component. If the marginal
cost needs to be measured in order to define if any rate flexibility exist on
the intended route using the proposed equation, then, a freight manager must
proceed as follows: 12/4=3 as the freight initial constant of cost in its decimal
equivalent of F= (U^.25 S^.25 C^.25 D^.25).
This equation can be
applied not just to obtain marginal return on each freight cost component but also,
to measure profit margin and overall productivity by replacing the corresponding
exponent(s) with different testing values for the model.
Comparing values obtained between the model
and those calculated based on break-even point, rate per ton mile, rate per
trip, rate per day and so on can vary with each method of calculation but once
the factors are obtained and entered in a computer or interactive worksheet it
can become a very useful tool for improving productivity.
Arguably, optimization
can also be accomplish using LaGrange multipliers, although, it requires a lot
more algebraic manipulation which makes its handling weighty, moreover, with the proposed method individual
variables can be isolate and evaluated and this feature cannot be replicated
using the LaGrange multipliers.
Alfonso Llanes
May 20, 2016
References
MATHEMATICAL
MODELS OF TRANSPORTATION AND NETWORKS, (2007). Anna Nagurney John F. Smith
Memorial Professor Department of Finance and Operations Management Isenberg
School of Management University of Massachusetts
Amherst, Massachusetts.
Mathematical
Models in Economics (2007)
Filipe, Jesus; Adams, F. Gerard (2005).
"The Estimation of the Cobb-Douglas Function: A Retrospective View".
Eastern Economic Journal 31 (3): 427–445.
Optimization
Methods in Economics (2001). John Baxley Department of Mathematics
Wake Forest University. Winston-Salem NC.
Discrete
Optimization Algorithms (1983). Maciej M. Syslo, Narsingh Deo, and Janusz
S. Kowalik.
Prentice-Hall,
Inc., Englewood Cliffs, NJ.
Calculus: Early
Transcendentals (2008). Sixth edition. Stewart, James).. McMaster
University, Ontario, Canada.
Maritime Economics,
Third Edition2009. Stopford, Martin. Roudledge, Keble College Oxford,
England.
Where are the hard
knapsack problems?. Technical Report (2003/08). Pisinger, David. Department
of Computer Science, University of Copenhagen, Copenhagen, Denmark.
No comments:
Post a Comment